您的位置: 首页 » 法律资料网 » 法律法规 »

山东省人民政府参事参政议政试行办法

时间:2024-06-28 19:38:07 来源: 法律资料网 作者:法律资料网 阅读:8208
下载地址: 点击此处下载

山东省人民政府参事参政议政试行办法

山东省政府


山东省人民政府参事参政议政试行办法
山东省政府


(1990年8月13日山东省人民政府印发)


第一条 为使省人民政府参事参政议政制度化、规范化,发挥参事在省政府工作中的咨询作用,根据中共中央和国务院的有关规定,制定本办法。
第二条 省人民政府参事室是省人民政府所属的一个工作部门,是一个具有统战性、咨询性的机构。省人民政府参事的基本职责是参政议政,在省政府工作中发挥咨询作用。
第三条 省政府参事参政议政的目的是,反映各界人士对省政府工作的意见和要求,进一步促进省政府决策的科学化、民主化,提高依法决策水平;推动省政府机关改进工作,提高效率,克服官僚主义,加强廉政建设;体现共产党领导的多党合作和政治协商制度,发扬社会主义民主,
调动一切积极因素,为富民兴鲁献计献策。
第四条 省政府参事参政议政的主要内容:
(一)了解省政府工作的方针、政策及计划实施情况,进行调查研究,提出意见和建议;
(二)参与讨论省政府提交省人民代表大会审议的《政府工作报告》草案,提出意见;
(三)参与研究地方性法规草案和省政府规章草案,提出意见;
(四)参加省政府有关部门组织的对人民群众关心和反映强烈的问题的调查活动,提出意见和建议;
(五)密切同各界人士的联系,向省政府反映他们的意见和要求;
(六)参加爱国统一战线工作,为统一祖国献计出力;
(七)承担省政府领导交办的有关事项。
第五条 省政府参事参政议政的主要形式:
(一)参事室以《参事建议》、《参事反映》以及其他形式,将参事调查研究的意见和建议报送省政府领导或有关部门;
(二)省政府领导根据工作需要,不定期地向参事通报工作情况,听取参事的意见和建议;
(三)参事根据分工列席省政府全体会议和全体扩大会议,以及省政府领导认为需要参事列席的其他会议;
(四)省政府法制局可将征求有关部门意见的法律、法规、规章草案,同时送参事室征求参事的意见;
(五)参事可以直接向省政府领导人反映情况、提出意见和建议。
第六条 省政府参事应努力学习马列主义、毛泽东思想,学习党和政府的方针、政策,学习国家的法律法规,坚持四项基本原则,反对资产阶级自由化,同党中央在政治上保持一致;应深入实际调查研究,密切同各界人士的联系;积极参加有关会议,阅读有关文件,不断提高参政议政
水平。
第七条 本试行办法自发布之日起试行。



1990年8月13日

Student:Dayong Zhou

dayong_77@hotmail.com


The Collectivizationa and De-collectivization in Rural China

周大勇 (Zhou,Dayong)

Abstract: the process of de-collectivization took place 25 years ago, however it was uncompleted, which determined that china has to make great effort to continue his rural reform, in order to liberate the peasant and the status of rural region as the Party promised. In China, the non-privatization reform occurred along with the de-collectivization was a uncompleted reform, which remains the defects of both collectivization and small-scale peasant economy, therefore it restricts the development of the rural society, however, the current system seems unable also reluctantly to change it. This paper intents to introduce the process of the collectivization and the most important rural reform in this century, namely the de-collectivization, the demonstrates the progression of de-collectivization, its characters as well as the problems left to be solve.
Keywords: collectivization De-collectivization collective ownership incomplete

Foreword
I am pleased that I am allowed to write the term paper about China. China was influenced by Marxism and walked in detour of history for half century. Before Marxism bankrupted in former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe countries, China had adopted a different way to reform from those countries. Because of the difference in aspects of historical evolution, political forms and natural environment, it’s hard to compare the rural society of China with these former socialism countries directly, also, the progression of collectivization and its end are different in two continents.
Rural china before collectivization
Collectivization was a mark system of the socialist state. Although in the era of Utopian socialism, Robert Owen for example has already attempted to set up the collective farm, but it wasn’t pursued by force strength of government. Even the founder of communism Marx didn’t agree that communism could be realized in undeveloped countries with extremely poor productivity . It was Russia, the serf country, in which Communist took power without adequate preparation; collectivization was implemented by force, in order to consolidate the rule in grass-root countryside. This experience has influenced China and Eastern Europe, because one of the merits of the collectivization lies in being easy to be managed, the other lies in being easy to deprive peasants.
China was a backward country, which suffered from ignorance and war for centuries. Throughout the centuries some 80 to 90 percent of the Chinese population were farmers and live in one of some 900,000 villages, which have an average population of from 1,000 to 2,000 people. Villages were not self-contained, self-sufficient units. Clusters of villages centered on small market towns, which linked them to the wider economy and society by providing not only opportunities to buy and sell but also opportunities for entertainment, information, social life, and a host of specialized services. The traditional Chinese elite, often referred to in English as the gentry dispersed across the country and often lived in rural areas, where they were the dominant figures on the local scene, normally ruled villages. Although they held land, which they rented to tenant farmers, they neither possessed large estates like European nobles nor held hereditary titles. However, they traditionally interpreted central policies and national values for villagers. As in feudal relationship, the peasants and gentry live depend on each other. Gentry provided land to poor peasants and tenant, and work with rich and middle peasants to secure the order in village, for instance opening school and building basic infrastructures to maintain there social status. In Chinese history, at the beginning of very dynasty, the land relationship between landlord and poor peasants were comparably fair, that meant, peasant have parcel farmland to live on. But land tended to be concentrated on end every dynasty, then there might be a peasant uprising led to a new dynasty and retribution of land. This is the basic clue of social evolution in China before communist period.
After the Chinese Communist Party came into power in mainland, it had to keep its promise, which it made during the period of war to encourage the peasant to join the army, that it would gave peasant their own land. The first major action took place from 1940s to early 1950s. June 1950, a new Land Reform Law of new People’s Republic was promulgated and stipulated nullification of the feudal land ownership system, and institutionalization of the system of land ownership by peasants, in which the Party sent agents to every village to carry out the land reform policy. This in itself was an unprecedented show of political power and the resolution of transform an old society. The reform was successful, because the peasants supported the policy; most of them had been waiting for the reform for long time. In the light of the reform law, land were redistribute from the landlords, land-owning trusts or wealthier families to the poor segments in the same village; village elites, who might be expected to go up against the Party and its programs were brought down; new leadership was established by poor peasants who showed the most loyalty to the party's goals; instead of kinship group or patron-client ties, class status became new relationship among villagers.
the process of Collectivization
However, the Party’s leaders were not satisfied with the privatization of land, at one hand, such ownership, according to the doctrine of socialism, should have been abolished in the state of socialism, at another hand, private ownership of small peasantry had no function of property accumulation for the country. At that time, in order to accelerate the construction of socialism, China had launched The First Five-Year Plan after the Soviet model; heavy industry development was profound stressed since the leaders of Communist Party regard socialist country as a country with developed industry sectors. However, the situation in early 1950s was not ideal for a new country. Pressing of needs for food in a country with burgeoning population, domestic capital for investment, and purchase of Soviet-supplied technology, capital equipment, and military hardware. To satisfy these needs, collectivize agriculture was put forward. Collectivization was regard as a method to turn countryside to stabile backing, which can be managed as semi-military and had rare contact with outside, so that the government could press the price of agricultural products by means of scissors difference between cities and countryside, and seize huge numbers of profit from agriculture economies to support the industrialization in city. At the same time, the government had already nationalized banking, industry, and even trade. Private enterprise was already virtually abolished in national wide.
Despite internal disagreement as to the speed of collectivization, preliminary collectivization was launched since 1952. China's peasantry saw Chairman Mao and the Communist Party as heroic much more than Russia's peasantry had seen Stalin and the Bolsheviks as heroes, and through 1956 the peasantry cooperated with the Party. There was none of the resistance and warfare that had accompanied the collectivization of agriculture in the Soviet Union.
The collectivization of agriculture was basically completed with the establishment of the people's communes in 1958. The People’s Commune system was defined as a unity of politics and production, in which all members of the commune jointly owned property. Essentially, the commune system was based on private contract of its members and the principle of voluntaries and mutual benefit, however, it turned out yet as coercive institutional arrangement, which was made by government with political power. In the movement to achieve the People’ s Commune, peasants had no choice whether or not to join.
Communes were designed as large, embracing scores of villages created by combining some 20 or 30 advanced producers' cooperatives of 20,000 to 30,000 members on average, in some cases the membership varied from as few as 6,000 to over 40,000. It was instituted as an organization with functions of the lowest level of local government and the highest level of organization in agricultural production. Communes consisted of three organizational levels: the central commune administration; the production brigade , and the production team, which generally consisted of around thirty families. This kind of institution was an organization of hierarchies, in which the commune acted as political unit and top manager, the brigades played role of co-coordinators between the commune and the basic production teams. The production team was basic units of production and accounting. Since the people’s commune system was a tool established to extract resources from agriculture sector for industrialization, as a result, it neglected peasants’ incentive completely. In order to let the people’s commune system run, the central government designed an relative effective mechanism to encourage managers in each hierarchy to work enthusiastically, yet, in each level, the managers were treated differently and there was a clear difference in aspects of identity and welfare between the managers of the commune and of the brigades or production teams.
The commune was defined as administrative organ and executed the central government’s orders, and paid from central government’s budget, therefore the managers in the level of commune were “state cadres” , that means they were formal governmental officials and got wage monthly. These state cadres could be promoted and became officials of governmental divisions in higher level. Brigades and production teams were collective economic organizations, their running expenses came from production teams’ tribute. Managers in brigades level were called “collective cadres” . They were remunerated in their own production teams according to their labor quotas. Their wage was paid in the form of products instead of money. Managers in production teams were“team cadres”, they were also members of the production team. They worked as peasant like their workmates, and were paid in products according to labor quotas. Team cadres could be promoted to collective cadres. Collective and team cadres had little possibilities to be promoted and became members of state cadres. Nevertheless, as collective and team cadres had some privileges. For example, collective managers had the power of assigning state’s delivery quotas and production tasks among production teams, they determined who could enrolled in state-owned factories, universities and army. The production team managers executed the power of assigning work and distributing products among collective members. Furthermore, in the period of many political movements and class struggles, the identity of cadre could protect their families, relatives and themselves from being denounced and bullied (Tan, 1999).
At beginning, the commune itself was decorated as the representation of socialist society and had all merits of public ownership. Although nearly all the private property had been deprived, peasants had to praise the new system profusely. it was true, most poor peasants found that their lives changed, by eating in the public dining they didn’t need to worry about their own budget anymore, and by working together, they were not necessary to try their best. Following propaganda appeared in newspapers everyday:
The public dining halls are distributed in a way that members need walk only a few minutes from their homes to take their meals. On the freshly whitewashed walls of the one on Shihfuchien Street, a typical establishment, there is a big slogan in red, which reads, "High Spirits for Higher Production!" Its kitchen, to which the visitor is drawn by the aroma of food and the clatter of pots, is managed by Tu Hsiu-chen, the first volunteer cook, who has since learned large-scale catering from the chef at one of the city's restaurants.
The walls of the spacious dining room are decorated with paintings, as a home might be. Its tables and chairs, though simple, are scrubbed to a shining cleanliness. The food is fresh and tasty -- vegetables are grown by the commune itself. The staff make a special point of studying the diet and preferences of old people, children, nursing mothers and members with ailments. There is a separate room for parents with small children, provided with low tables for the little ones.( People’s Daily, 1958)
However, in practice, this ideal, extremely centralized form commune didn’t keep running well in most areas. Very soon it became clear that in most cases the communes were too clumsy to carry out successfully all the managerial and administrative functions that were assigned to them. The cooperative led to low-efficiency, the advantages of large-scale productivity didn’t arrive as peasants anticipated, productivity began to drop and discontent emerged. The reason lies in insufficient utilization of resources and lack of incentive of peasants. At one hand, the output of cooperation comes from all members’ work, in which the tribute of single household is difficult to be measured. So that opportunism like shirking happened naturally very frequently. An effective way to prevent shirking is to have all members supervised, but the seasonal work and spatial diversity of agricultural productive activities make it difficult to totally supervise. At the other hand, although brigade and production team cadres were obliged to complete state’s planning and all kinds of deliveries, the control right and residual claim of the people’s commune system were in the state’s hand, these cadres at grass-level could not design any reasonable incentive mechanism to encourage peasants to work hard and produce according to reasonable natural condition, such as soil, irrigation and farm year. The way left for brigade and team cadres was to punish peasants by struggling against them or maltreatment. But the brigade and team cadres also belonged to members of production teams, they and their families lived in the same community with their subordinates as well, so punishing peasants could also make themselves in trouble. Moreover, under the property rights structure of the commune system, the rest of output was not belong to the commune, brigade or even production team, but to the governments of higher level. This made the supervisors’ effort unrelated to any reward. As a result, even the supervisor himself has not enough incentive to work and shirk himself sometimes. In a word, under such conditions of poor supervision, in which all the work was distributed equally among all members at the lowest level--production team, shirking became every member’s rational choice and further weakening the efficiency of the system (Lin,1990).
De-collectivization
To prevent peasants from slow down, shrinking and escaping in work, and assure the system could keep on moving, the party collected all productive equipments and forbid members in people’s commune engaging in private production and business on the one hand, and at same time deprived peasants’ right of migrating from countryside to city or between districts by means of household registration on the other hand. Nevertheless, such policies had no effect on improving incentive of peasants, but they formed at least political press on very member of people’s commune, because it turned out that everyone’s only routine is to stay in the commune and finish one’s task. Without the right to leave or get better than others, peasants commonly chose to work with little effort, e.g. a passive method, to evade production tasks assigned by leader. Little accumulation and shirking made countryside widely fall into poverty , rare rural region had good conditions to develop industry or to improve commerce, infrastructures went worse, productivity sank quickly. The most serious crisis for agricultural collectivization happened between 1959 and 1961. GNP decreased from 213.8 billion Yuan in 1958 to 180.0 billion Yuan in 1962, with an average annual reduction of 15.1% in gross industrial production value and an average annual reduction of 19.3% in gross agricultural production value from 1958 to 1960. Owing to the serious shortage of food, a great famine took place in the whole country and at least 30 million residents died (Tan, 2000). Discontent with such system broke out, in some areas, peasants didn’t want to relied so heavily on orders from above and made so little allowance for local conditions or local initiative. The severe crisis forced the Party to adjust their policies. From 1961 on, commune functions were reduced to administration and co-ordination, production team was confirmed as the basic unit of accounting, certain production decision making was delegated to production teams, which were allowed to retain some income to overcome problems of egalitarianism; households again allowed to have small private plots and sidelines for planting vegetables, and a limited opening markets for transaction between urban and rural areas. However, these adjustments didn’t mean to change the system of people’s commune, but only to prevent peasants from rebel. From 1966 to 1976 China suffered the disaster of Cultural Revolution , there were large institutional swings took place in this period, in which co-operative moved from small to large and from team to brigade to commune again, local free markets, sidelines and private plots was prohibited again, and political factors had a great influence on production decisions.
In late 1970s, after the Leader Chairman Mao passed away, the requirement for improving agricultural productivity came alive. Administrators in provincial-level units with extensive regions of low yields and consequent low standards of living began experimenting with new forms of tenure and production. To avoid frontal conflicts of wide scope with government’s policies and the main ideology, a gradual approach was adopted. The first step of reform was to divide the production team into groups and to fix yield quotas for each group. Each group signed a contract with production team, the contractual items included the conditions of using land, laborers, farm tools and draft animals, the expenditure, labor contribution, rewards for excessive labor contribution and so on. After completing the tasks assigned by the production team, the output could be distributed among work groups according to their labor quotas. And then, the further solution was put forward, namely the typical form of fixing quotas called “all-round contract”, which was initiated by a few brave peasant secretly in Fengyang county of Anhui province. this contract regulated, household was allowed to cultivated a certain parcel farmland in the group, if grain quotas assigned by the state and the collective accumulation were accomplished, the household could own all the residual output. In the light of the contract, peasants were given directly stimulation to produce. The experiment was deemed successful and popular, and it soon spread to all districts.
At another side, political situation was appropriate with the reform form below. In the Eleventh National Party Congress, held August 12- 18, 1977 proclaimed the formal end of the Cultural Revolution, blamed it entirely on the Gang of Four , and reiterated that "the fundamental task of the party in the new historical period is to build China into a modern, powerful socialist country by the end of the twentieth century." The reformer Deng Xiaoping was elected as vice chairman and back to political stage and suggested a series of reform plans, though many contradictions still were apparent, change of policy was regarded as necessary. Rehabilitations of Deng's associates and others sympathetic to these reform plans were stepped up. Not only were some of those purged during the Cultural Revolution returned to power, but also individuals who had fallen from favor as early as the mid-1950s were rehabilitated. It was a time of increased political activism.
In November 1980, the Central Committee of Communist Party of China issued the document Some Issues of Further Reinforcing and Improving the Responsibility System in Agricultural Production. This article manifest the first time that the Party accepted the production responsibility systems developing in practice. In the document fixed output quotas of farmland for each group and responsibility contracts in some specialized obligations were indicated, at the same time, the fixed output quotas for household was also regarded as positive. Under the encouragement of government’s policy and related support measures, plenty of production responsibility systems developed very rapidly in rural areas. In 1981, a wide deeper reform called fixing the contribute quote for each household (bao gan dao hu), which was much more radical, was implemented. In accordance to the system, all collective lands in production teams were to be distributed among households based on their population or laborers. The households could manage the lands, made production decisions by themselves, and bore the results. When tasks assigned by upper government and the collective accumulation, e.g. a certain quantity of grain and livestock, were completed, the remained products could be owned by the households and not distributed among members in the production team. Moreover, if the household made sure that they have enough ration, they had right to sell the left grain to state owned agricultural enterprises or consume them as they want, usually feeding livestock or making wine for example. That meant the model from Fengyang was finally admitted by Party. In October 1983, the Party and the State Counsel issued the document Notice of Separating the Co-operative from Politics and Setting Up the Township Government and required the cooperative to separate from local government. The act ordered that the people's communes were replaced by administrative townships. By the end of 1984, 98% of production teams had taken the reform of Household Responsibility System. It was until then, the collectivization system was dismantled completely.
Some Characters of De-collectivization and Problems left
No restitution
Yet, de-collectivization and the implement of the household responsibility system is neither a reform of the ownership of land nor a process of privatization. As we have mentioned above, after the Communist Party set up its own government in 1949, it started land reform and distributed lands to the poor from landlords and rich peasants. Peasant acquired parcels of land according to the labor forces, then land were registered under name of each household. Before the eve of collectivization, most of lands in rural China were legally privately owned. But when de-collectivization began, peasants did not get back their former lands again. The household responsibility system only distribute the right of manage and benefit of lands among households according to their population or laborers. So, the de-collectivization in China did not like that in most of East European countries such as Bulgaria, Czech, Hungary, Poland, Romania and Slovakia, but like that in Albania. That is to say, there was no restitution of land. However, in former East European Countries, whether restitution was implemented or not, the de-collectivization had symbiosis with privatization. In China, although during the process of de-collectivization there were in reality some opinions that lands should be restituted, such voices were not accepted, nor even discussed.
The reasons why restitution of land in the de-collectivization of rural China did not happen may lie in some historic reasons. First of all, although peasants in China had private ownership over lands before the collectivization, large percent of peasants owned farmlands that did not belong to them before, they obtain them from political transformation. Theoretically, violence can’t consist the legal reason of transfer of ownership over real estate, therefore even after the terrorize during the land reform at beginning of 1950s, the private ownership of lands, which was made out by the communist government, had not yet became stable and commonly accepted. However, the former landlord class had rooted off during the political movement, land contacts and register books of land title had been destroyed, no one dare to challenge the power of Communist Party anymore. Since the collectivization began soon after the land reform, the new established owner relationship was broken again, when de-collectivization came about, without supports from the central government, most of peasants only took the household responsibility system as another chance of equally distributing lands, just like the land reform in 1949. As to descendants of former landlord class, they might have not forgotten the experience of their poor ancestors’: claiming private right before the Party which regarding public ownership as universal truth is a dangerous deal.
Secondly, different from most country in former communist east European countries , in which farmers’ nominal ownership of lands was remained, even though their lands were requisitioned in collective farms without any payment, and so that it was easy for peasants in these countries to take back the land when the collective farms went over. On the contrary, in China, private ownership of land was totally abolished as soon as the people’s commune system was set up, after 20 years, the collective ownership had already fest basis. As a result, the transaction costs of restitution so high as to wipe it out. That means, even a peasant want to take back the former farmland which belonged to them, it’s very hard to him to collect the relevant evidences to support his claim, moreover, there was no legal justice process to support such application. So normal farmer would rather to accept the Household Responsibility System.
Finally, the key reason lies in the socialism system itself. Even though the Communist Party of had poor performance in leading the country and its people to wealth and happiness during socialist revolution, Chinese people have taken socialism as the characteristic of the country for grant, after all the slogan “ Socialism saved China” has been deeply impressed. So that even after the Culture Revolution, most people still propped up the Party. The Party led the rural reform and decided the de-collectivization. However, the reform is a “liberation of the rural productivity”, which suit the requirement of the Party. Because the Chinese Communist Party insisted that his mission is to realize socialism, and socialism is based on public ownership system. Collective ownership was deemed as one form of public ownership in rural regions, so that as China kept on the road of realizing socialism, “land in rural areas belong to collective” was certainly remained after rural reform, and regulated in the Constitution of 1982, which is valid till now.
At the time of de-collectivization, the dissolution of people’s commune and the wide implement of responsibility system were regard as a great innovation. According to the statistic, The Household Responsibility System did bring about a more prosperous agriculture in China. From 1978 to 1984, grain output in China increased at an annual average rate of 5% and the gross value of agriculture by 7.7% (Lin, 1997). In contrast with former European countries, the de-collectivization seems bring more benefit to Chinese peasants at beginning. So that at that time, rare peasant did realize that such a reform without transformation of ownership was incompletely. However, The natural shortcomings of the de-collectivization would surely bring a series of problems.
institutional problem: land distribution
As we showed above, the de-collectivization ran smoothly and the introduction of Household Responsibility System has got a great success, although it could not address everything as only an institutional innovation. After several years of practice, it has been already proved that there are a number of weaknesses and limitations remained from the incompletely de-collectivization. One has to confirm, that the collective ownership and contract system led to the inequity in both economic and political features.
In economic view, during the de-collectivization, farmland was distributed to individual households in form of fragmented farming units. The principle of land distribution was derived directly from collective ownership. Farmland in a village was owned by all of its members collectively. As a result, every member had equal right to claim on distribution of the land according to certain norm, which was based primarily on the size of the peasant family. In reality of China with abundant population and limited land, the amount can be distributed to each household was very small. Moreover, land differed from each other in terms of soil fertility, irrigation conditions, location and so on. In many cases, a household had to obtain pieces of land from each of the grades. as a result, the sum was not only insufficient but also disjointed and scattered around villages. Large areas of cultivated land were wasted in the form of paths and boundaries separating households' contract field. A survey conducted by the Chinese Ministry of Agriculture indicated that in 1986, among 7983 sample villages from 29 provinces, average cultivated area per household was 0.466 ha (7 mu) fragmented into 5.85 plots, each plot on average 0.08 ha (1.2 mu) (Ministry of Agriculture of China, 1993) . This fragmented structure of family farming has remained largely untouched after implement of contract system and has detained the possibilities of using relatively advanced mechanical agricultural equipment and infrastructures.
Under such system, farmers turned to be short-term in action. According to the distribute rule of land in household responsibility system, land is to distribute depended only on villager status, babies and villagers' new-comer such as newly married bride from other villages were all eligible claimants, which having equal rights to share equal amounts of land in this village; on the contrary, when a villager left or died, the right of land claim would automatically withdraw. As population increased, villages had to readjust the distribution structure, which further subdivided the farmland . The endless redistribution of farmland resulted in many problems, including: 1) the situation of a small and fragmented farming structure further deteriorated; 2) worrying about the risk of losing their land as well as investment, farmers had little incentives to improve land conservation and agricultural infrastructure - irrigated land, one of the most significant components of agricultural infrastructure in China, remained almost unchanged during the 1980s; 3) farmers over-exploited the soil to pursue short-term profits; 4) the course of land redistribution was also costly, it required labor and time in organization and execution. (Chen, 1999)
Another problem is that farmland was generally badly endowed with the appropriate human capital. Since egalitarianism was the general leading principle rule, which gave little consideration to interfamily differences such as labor capability, education and individual preference . As a result, some large households with a incomplete labor force could have comparably much more land to cultivate, meanwhile other smaller households, above all those specialized in agriculture, could have only inadequate land for full employment. Such kind of problem was much worse in rural areas experiencing rapid township or village industry and urbanization. In those region there was often deterioration in the agricultural labor force since most of capable labors tended not to work at home as a farmer. There were many who did not give priority to cultivation and at times even let the land lie unused. Consequently, the farmland was underutilized .
Upon preceding analyzing, we can see that, in order to pursue egalitarianism on surface in distribution of land, in the process of the de-collectivization sacrificed economic efficiency. Thus, if the land was private, then those difference arouse from distribution will decease after enough time, because the free market will lead to equal efficiency through the choose of market. However, such political background lacked from beginning on, so that the shortcoming of a non-privatization de-collectivization can’t be corrected or even be enlarged because of problem of political system.
One of the main reason is political structure over the collective ownership. First at grass-root level, it was usually the village head, who takes the power to decide distribution since decentralization. So that the cadre family or their relations will surely benefit from the distribution. Having a cadre in the family seems to be a certain prerogative in using their political status to accumulate wealth. At one hand, Village cadres may allocate more fertile parts of the village land to themselves and determined more favorable grain sales quotas for themselves. And also, cadres have more opportunity to build personal relationship with higher level and other important departments, rural credit banks or transportation companies for example, so that they have more chance to obtain material benefit than normal peasants. As we see, most of collective enterprises and private economies in rural areas have tight relationship with local governments, at the basic level, with villager cadres, most rural enterprisers are villager leader themselves. Furthermore, cadres and their relations generally tend to break the policy of birth control, because they are capable to support more family members, and their kin will strengthen their economic and political power in return.
At another hand, though according to the election regulation of rural cadre in china, these village cadre should be elected directly by villagers, who have common interest in the community, this rule has been almost never put into practice. Under one Party system and public ownership system, all important resources are gathered in the Party’s hand, as a result, instead of election, the opinion from higher level plays a significant role, in order to carry ort the policy of Party efficiently. In fact, two factors determine the candidates in appointment of village head, one is the relationship with official of higher level, and the other is kinship. Consequently, cadre family takes all advantages to maintain their power and status through such appointment. So, cadres in rural China don’t represent the benefit of their village members, but the power of the Party as well as the family, there is no possibility for peasants to claim equality or save their from suffering as a peasant.
In a word, after a short flourish in rural China, which came along with the de-collectivization and the implement of Household Responsibility System, most peasants have to face the irrational occupation and distribution system of farmland and the political system, which is impossible to change. Besides there was strict limitation prevent peasants from abandoning their responsible land and rushing into cities, so that the peasants found it is hard to change their situation or turn it more better and free. This may explain why in rural china exists always the tendency of over population but the income of household began to decrease only after less than 10 years from the de-collectivization. As a result, land reform in China has emerged as a difficult issue in rural areas of exchange between social equality and economic efficiency. It seems obvious that since the mid-1980s the wide rural society has been caught in this predicament: where social equality or equity worsened, and at same time economic efficiency held back.. According to statistics, average net income in countryside has been slowed down for years. In 2000, the household average income only reached 272 dollars, but the Gini coefficient in China base in urban and rural areas rose from 0.21 in 1978 to more than 0. 46.

国务院办公厅转发国家计委关于国家产业政策贯彻执行情况和下一步工作意见报告的通知

国务院办公厅


国务院办公厅转发国家计委关于国家产业政策贯彻执行情况和下一步工作意见报告的通知
国务院办公厅



国务院同意国家计委《关于国家产业政策贯彻执行情况和下一步工作意见的报告》,现转发给你们,请认真贯彻执行。

附:国家计委关于国家产业政策贯彻执行情况和下一步工作意见的报告
《国务院关于当前产业政策要点的决定》(以下简称《决定》自去年3月颁布以来,配合治理整顿和深化改革工作,已开始发挥作用。各地方、各部门在实际工作中越来越感到产业政策的重要,在制定计划,组织生产、压缩固定资产投资、利用外资、安排进出口和发放贷款等方面,正
在逐步重视贯彻国家产业政策,努力改善我国产业结构、产品结构的不合理状况。
现将国家产业政策贯彻执行情况和下一步工作意见报告如下。
一、国家产业政策贯彻执行情况
(一)认真制订了实施办法。各地方、各部门按照《决定》要求,在认真组织学习和广泛宣传《决定》的基础上,做了大量的调查研究和组织协调工作。到目前为止,已有七十八个地方和部门提出了实施办法(含送国家计委征求意见稿),其中地方四十个,行业主管理部门二十五个,
经济综合部门十三个。这些实施办法经过地方人民政府和部(局、行)办公会议反复讨论和修改,基本体现了国家产业政策的精神,在一定程度上增强了《决定》的可操作性,较好地起到了统一思想认识和协调政策的作用。
许多地方和专业部门在制订实施办法时,认真按照《决定》的要求,结合地区、部门的特点,确定了本地区、本部门发展重点和限制重点,列出了限制生产、淘汰生产和保证生产的产品目录,提出了有保有压、区别对待的实施保障政策,有的还列出了重点企业和项目名单。
综合经济部门所制订的实施办法,以国家产业政策为依据,相继提出了一些目标一致的实施保障政策。例如,银行提出了调整固定资产贷款差别利率办法,并按照国家产业政策调整贷款结构,对企业进行分类排队。财政部制订了固定资产投资方向调节税的方案。物资部制订了重要物资
分配供应序列和进入市场交易实行倾斜销售的重要物资目录。经贸部提出了统一的外贸产业政策实施办法方案。关于指导外商投资方向的规定正在拟订中。国家工商行政管理局修订了年检登记、严格市场管理和广告管理的办法。国家统计局调整了一些统计产品目录。
有些行业主管部门提出,应适当集中对国家产业政策限制的产业、产品建设、改造项目的审批权限。
(二)研究制订了一些产品的规模经济政策、专业化协作政策、发展企业集团的政策、利用国际产业结构重组机遇的对策。具体组织制定和组织实施了限制生产铝门窗、易拉罐的政策。
(三)国家产业政策在结构调整中已开始发挥作用。一年来,在治理整顿方针的指导下,通过多方面采取综合措施,生产结构(主要是产品结构)、固定资产投资结构、企业组织结构和进出口结构也初步有所调整。农业和工业发展速度的差距缩小;能源、原材料、交通运输相对得到加
强,一般加工工业品和高档消费品的生产得到相应的抑制;小铁合金、小棉纺等高耗能和高耗料建设项目得到一定控制,能源、交通运输等方面项目投资比重上升;一些地方和部门对少数企业分别实行了关停并转,同时加强了对乡镇企业的引导;工业制成品出口比重上升,部分高档消费品
的进口比上年减少。
二、存在的问题
我国产业结构不协调,产业素质不高的问题是严重的,需要依靠科学的产业政策,用较长的时间予以解决。当前的问题是,国家产业政策中已经明确的一些规定尚未得到认真贯彻,主要表现在有些该限制或停止的内容未得到有效控制。如有的地方和部门在生产上仍把国家定点个的汽车
、摩托车、小棉纺、小毛纺、白酒、吸尘器、汽柴油发电、小凝汽式火电、小染料、小铁合金、土焦等列为重点给予支持;在建设上把国家定点外的汽车、彩管及玻壳、聚酯、冰柜和压缩机等制冷设备、空调器、录相机、传真机、照像机、洗衣机、电子元器件等作为发展重点,继续新建或
扩建;在进口方面,一些严格限制或禁止进口的空调器、摩托车、电视机、录相机、录音机、化妆品、钟表、眼镜、乐器、食品、服装等仍禁而不止。企业组织结构的调整,阻力甚大,尚无明显变化。
造成以上这些问题的原因是多方面的,较为深层次的原因是价格、财政分配体制、信贷管理体制、财政包干、企业承包不够完善,社会统筹保险制度尚未建立,等等。这些都有待于通过深化改革逐步加以解决。还有一些工作上的原因,主要是:(一)一些地方和部门对产业政策的组织
实施工作,还不够重视,有的至今还未明确专人和相应机构负责产业政策工作。(二)一些实施保障政策还缺乏有效联动。(三)国家产业政策中还缺乏地区分类指导政策。(四)在组织实施产业政策上还不够及时有力。这些都对国家产业政策有效实施带来一定影响。
三、继续抓好国家产业政策的组织实施工作
产业政策是我国计划管理的组成部分,是计划经济与市场调节相结合的一种经济管理方式。1990年,要把进一步制定和实施产业政策放到重要日程上来,首先要继续搞好《决定》的组织实施工作。
(一)继续完善实施办法。李鹏总理在七届人大三次会议上作的政府工作报告中,再一次强调了这项工作。我们要善始善终地完成,并坚定不移地贯彻落实。在贯彻落实中,要突出抓好综合经济部门和各省、自治区、直辖市落实经济调控措施,组织行业主管理部门会同地方提出分地区
的指导意见。
(二)根据中央关于“各行各业要对现有的国营大中型企业进行分类排队”的精神,各地方、各部门应立即着手拟订重点支持的大中型工业企业分类排队名单。除对少数企业实行“双保”外,对多数企业在治理整顿期间要有一个大致排列,以便在外部条件发生变化时,在资金、物资的
供应上有个一致的先后次序。
(三)按照国家产业政策调整银行贷款结构。当前,有效实施产业政策的重要环节之一是要调整银行信贷结构。目前的资金呆滞与紧缺并存的状况,只有疏导得当才能缓解。对此,我们建议,按照国家产业政策对银行贷款进行一次全面的清理。我们的资金有限,只能保证产业政策重点
支持的生产和建设。对产业政策规定限制和停止的生产和建设,原则上不再提供信贷支持,已发放的贷款逐步收回;并通过多种办法促使其并、转以至关、停,对因此而发生的困难只能通过补助、救济等办法加以帮助。由于这项工作难度较大,可以先搞试点,取得经验,再逐步扩展。
(四)组织地方、部门按照国家产业政策疏导市场。要保证生活必需品的生产;支持增加市场适销产品的生产;保证重点建设和改造项目的资金供应,以搞活为重点建设提供产品的企业的生产;要真正放开小商品的价格,以促使其增产;还要保证出口商品的生产。这些方面保证了,就
可以保持80%以上的企业的正常生产。对于高档消费品、一般产品和市场滞销积压的长线产品,则应由市场去调节,对假冒伪劣产品要坚决停产,这才有利于产业结构的调整。
(五)组织地方、部门按照国家产业政策检查预算外资金使用情况。预算外资金比重日益增大,其使用缺乏指导,投资方向失控,规模和结构不合理,是近几年造成重复建设、重复引进、资金使用效益低的重要原因之一,应对其使用方向是否符合国家产业政策进行认真检查并制定相应
政策予以引导。
(六)适当集中限制发展产品和少数问题较严重产品的建设和改造项目的审批权。凡国家产业政策严格限制的产品,一般不应按原产品新建、扩建和改造。国家按照产业政策和国民经济发展情况,定期或不定期公布需要加强控制建设和改造的产品目录。凡列入该目录产品的建设改造项
目,不论其规模大小、投资多少、资金来源、均需先报经国家行业归口部门核准后,再按现行限额以上及以下的固定资产投资审批程序进行审批。
除以上六条外,还要抓紧时机对物价、利率、税收、外汇、物资、工资等做出相应的政策调整,以利于产业政策的贯彻执行。
四、进一步开展产业政策工作的意见
我国的产业政策工作还刚刚开始,今后的工作是大量的。下一步产业政策工作,要在贯彻落实《决定》的同时,结合制定“八五”计划和十年规划纲要来进行。
(一)组织制定“八五”和十年产业政策
1、制定三年治理整顿期间调整结构的具体目标。各地方、各部门要在制定实施办法的基础上,进行测算和分析,限劣扶优,提出三年治理整顿中产业结构、产品结构调整的目标和数量要求,纳入“八五”和十年规划。
2、结合“八五”和十年规划的制定,组织制定“八五”和十年产业政策,包括产业结构政策、企业组织结构政策、地区产业结构政策、产业技术政策、实施保障政策和一些重点专项政策。不仅要注意量的协调,尤其要为提高产业结构的素质,创造世界第一流的产品服务作出战略安排
,提出具体实施方案,加快我国产业结构由粗放型向效益型转换。
3、“八五”期间产业序列将继续发挥导向作用。现行的《决定》对“八五”时期基本适用,但要根据实际情况的变化作相应调整。
(二)研究制定第三产业的政策要点。这是《决定》中确定的任务。我们已对我国第三产业的划分分类进行了一些研究,正组织有关部门抓紧进行政策的研究与制定。
(三)继续组织有关部门和专家对重大产品制定经济规模政策,经广泛协商一致后,通过一定法律程序颁布执行。要继续研究制定促进企业向专业化方向改组的政策。为落实国务院关于组建大型企业集团的指示精神,将组织研究拟定发展企业集团的规划设想及政策措施。
(四)组织多方面力量,研究制定产业分类管理办法。我们将会同有关部门和地方研究哪些产业必须通过市场竞争才能发展,哪些产业必需有一套明确、持久、有力的政策加以保护才能发展的区别政策,以实现产业政策的科学分类管理。
(五)组织研究利用国际产业结构重组的机遇。我们将对国际产业结构重组所引起的国际间资金、技术及产业转移的趋势进行深入研究,包括研究劳动密集型产品和某些大宗产品国际出口市场的变化,不失时机地抓住我国可能利用的机遇,以便于更好地利用国内、国外两种资源和两个
市场,促进我国产业结构的调整和升级。
以上报告如无不妥,请批转各地区、各部门执行。



1990年7月24日